References
↑1 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code §§ 16720, 16726; SC Manufactured Homes, Inc. v. Liebert, 162 Cal. App. 4th 68, 84 (2008) (“The [Act] prohibits conspiracies that unreasonably restrain trade.”); Fisherman’s Wharf Bay Cruise Corp. v. Superior Ct. of San Francisco, 114 Cal. App. 4th 309, 317 (2003) (“The Cartwright Act targets contracts in restraint of trade and promotes a free market by proscribing trusts.”). |
---|---|
↑2 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 17082. |
↑3 | See Cal. Code Civ. Proc. § 1032. |
↑4 | See SC Manufactured Homes, Inc. v. Liebert, 162 Cal. App. 4th 68, 84 (2008) (“The [Act] prohibits conspiracies that unreasonably restrain trade.”); Fisherman’s Wharf Bay Cruise Corp. v. Superior Ct. of San Francisco, 114 Cal. App. 4th 309, 317 (2003) (“The Cartwright Act targets contracts in restraint of trade and promotes a free market by proscribing trusts.”). |
↑5 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 16750; Carver v. Chevron U.S.A., Inc., 119 Cal. App. 4th 498, 504 (2004) (“The public policy implicit in the unilateral fee–shifting provision of section 16750, subdivision (a) is to encourage injured parties to broadly and effectively enforce the Cartwright Act in situations where they otherwise would not find it economical to sue. The Legislature clearly intended to give special treatment to antitrust claims under the Cartwright Act by creating this one-way fee-shifting right for a successful plaintiff but not for a defendant who successfully defends such a claim.”). |
↑6 | See Cal. Code Civ. Proc. § 1032. |
↑7 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code §§ 16750(c), 16760. |
↑8 | See Cal.Bus. & Prof. Code § 16750(g). |
↑9 | See Cal.Bus. & Prof. Code §§ 16754, 16755(a). |
↑10 | See Cal.Bus. & Prof. Code § 16755(a). |
↑11 | See In re Qualcomm Antitrust Litig., 292 F. Supp. 3d 948, 974 (N.D. Cal. 2017) (“The Cartwright Act proscribes ‘a combination of capital, skill or acts by two or more persons’ for an unlawful purpose. By its terms, the Act does not cover ‘wrongful conduct on the part of a single entity.’”) (quoting Bondi v. Jewels by Edwar, Ltd., 267 Cal. App.2d 672, 678 (1968)); Asahi Kasei Pharma Corp. v. CoTherix, Inc., 204 Cal. App. 4th 1, 11 (2012) (“[A]n indispensable element of any action under the Cartwright Act is proof of a ‘combination of resources of two or more independent interests for the purpose of restraining commerce and preventing market competition.’”) (quoting G.H.I.I. v. MTS, Inc., 147 Cal. App.3d 256, 266 (1983)). |
↑12 | See Asahi, 204 Cal. App. at 8 (“The Cartwright Act bans combinations, but single firm monopolization is not cognizable under the Cartwright Act.””); see also State of California ex rel. Van de Kamp v. Texaco, Inc., 46 Cal. 3d 1147, 1168–69 (1988) (an allegedly anticompetitive merger or acquisition cannot be challenged under the Act). |
↑13 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 16750(a); see also Stanislaus Food Prods. Co. v. USS-POSCO Indus., 782 F. Supp. 2d 1059, 1080 (E.D. Cal. 2011) (“Unlike the federal Sherman Act, the Cartwright Act grants indirect purchasers standing to sue, as well as direct purchasers.”). |
↑14 | See Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720, 728 (1977) (holding that indirect purchasers cannot bring suit to challenge price-fixing conspiracies or other violations of federal antitrust law). |
↑15 | See Cianci v. Superior Ct., 40 Cal. 3d 903, 919 (1985) (“While no direct sources for the legislative history of the Cartwright Act exist, we may reasonably assume that the Legislature’s intent was substantially similar to that of United States Senator John Reagan, who authored an unsuccessful bill offered as a substitute for what became the Sherman Act; the Cartwright Act is a near carbon copy of the Reagan bill. At the very least, the Sherman Act codified the common law. The Reagan bill was intended to reach further. The record of congressional debates reveals that the Reagan bill was designed not to narrow the scope of the Sherman Act but to broaden it.”). |
↑16 | see Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 16600 (non-compete covenants); §§ 17000–17101 (certain kinds of price discrimination, predatory pricing, and commercial boycotts |
↑17 | Of note, an eminent former justice on the California Supreme Court, the late Stanley Mosk, memorably explained in a partly dissenting opinion why the Act should be construed to reach anticompetitive mergers and acquisitions. See Texaco, 46 Cal. 3d at 1170–1192 (Mosk, J., concurring in part, dissenting in part). Justice Mosk’s interpretation, I believe, is substantively correct on all points and strongly supported by all of the following: (1) a proper reading of the common-law doctrines on restraint of trade that gave rise to the Act in the first place; (2) the Act’s own legislative history; and (3) basic precepts of statutory construction and English grammar. An adept antitrust practitioner might wish to raise the matter and urge the California Supreme Court to revisit its jurisprudence and adopt Justice Mosk’s interpretation, by which the Act would rightly reach anticompetitive mergers and acquisitions. Regardless, Justice Mosk’s separate opinion in Texaco is required reading for any practitioner who contemplates bringing a claim under the Act. |
↑18 | See Selevan v. New York Thruway Auth., 584 F.3d 82, 90 (2d Cir. 2009) (“In implementing the Commerce Clause, the Supreme Court has adhered strictly to the principle that the right to engage in interstate commerce is not the gift of a state, and that a state cannot regulate or restrain it. It flows from this principle that the negative or dormant implication of the Commerce Clause prohibits state taxation or regulation that discriminates against or unduly burdens interstate commerce and thereby impedes free private trade in the national marketplace.”). |
↑19 | See United States v. E. C. Knight Co., 156 U.S. 1, 25 (1895) (“[A] general restraint of trade has often resulted from combinations formed for the purpose of controlling prices by destroying the opportunity of buyers and sellers to deal with each other upon the basis of fair, open, free competition. Combinations of this character … have always been condemned as illegal because of their necessary tendency to restrain trade. Such combinations are against common right, and are crimes against the public.”) (Harlan, J., dissenting on other grounds); Sir William Erle, C.J., Court of Common Pleas, Law Relating to Trade Unions 5-7 (1869) (“Restraint of trade, according to a general principle of the common law, is unlawful…. [A]t common law every person has individually, and the public also have collectively, a right to require that the course of trade should be kept free from unreasonable obstruction…. [T]he right to a free course for trade is of great importance to commerce and productive industry, and has been carefully maintained by those who have administered the common law.”); United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co., 85 F. 271, 279 (6th Cir. 1898), aff’d after modification on other ground 175 U.S. 211 (1899) (“From early times it was the policy of Englishmen to encourage trade in England, and to discourage those voluntary restraints which tradesmen were often induced to impose on themselves by contract.”); Mitchel v. Reynolds, 1 P.Wms. 181, 190 (1711) (Parker, C.J.) (“The mischief which may arise from [restraints of trade are] (1) to the party by the loss of his livelihood and the subsistence of his family; (2) to the public by depriving it of an [sic] useful member. Another reason is the great abuses these voluntary restraints are liable to; as, for instance, from corporations who are perpetually laboring for exclusive advantages in trade, and to reduce it into as few hands as possible.”); see also Statute of Monopolies, Trin. 44 Eliz. lib. 11, f. 84, 85 (Subject to limited exceptions, “all grants of monopolies are against the ancient and fundamentall laws of this kingdome.”); Standard Oil Co. of New Jersey v. United States, 221 U.S. 1, 52–57 (1911) (referring to the history of monopolies in England, and explaining that state and federal courts in the United States generally deemed unauthorized monopolies to be “odious” to the law); United States v. Line Material Co., 333 U.S. 287, 308 (1948) (“Public policy has condemned monopolies for centuries.”) (citing The Case of Monopolies (Darcy v. Allein) 11 Co.Rep. 84-b). |
↑20 | See generally State of California ex rel. Van de Kamp v. Texaco, Inc., 46 Cal. 3d 1147, 1153–1169 (1988) (extended explanation of these points with citations to numerous authorities) (superseded by statute on other grounds as stated in Stop Youth Addiction, Inc. v. Lucky Stores, Inc., 17 Cal.4th 553, 570 (1998)); see also Cianci, 40 Cal. 3d at 919. |
↑21 | See Cellular Plus, Inc. v. Superior Ct., 14 Cal. App. 4th 1224, 1240 (1993) (“F]ederal cases interpreting the Sherman Act are applicable in construing our state laws. Accordingly, the appropriate use of federal cases interpreting the Sherman Act is as an aid in interpreting our own Cartwright Act.”); Fisherman’s Wharf, 114 Cal. App. 4th at 334 (“Since the Cartwright Act and the federal Sherman Act share similar language and objectives, California courts often look to federal precedents under the Sherman Act for guidance.”). |
↑22 | See Qualcomm, 292 F. Supp. 3d at 979 (“The California Supreme Court has held that the primary concern of the Cartwright Act is the elimination of restraints of trade and impairments of the free market.”); Clayworth v. Pfizer, Inc., 49 Cal. 4th 758, 783 (2010) (“From its inception, the Cartwright Act has always been focused on the punishment of violators for the larger purpose of promoting free competition…. The main purpose of the anti-trust laws is to protect the public from monopolies and restraints of trade….”); GreenCycle Paint, Inc. v. PaintCare, Inc., 250 F. Supp. 3d 438, 446 (N.D. Cal. 2017) (“The purpose of the Cartwright Act is to prevent any action which has as its purpose or effect an unreasonable restraint of trade.”) (emphasis in original); Corwin v. L.A. Newspaper Serv. Bureau, Inc., 22 Cal.3d 302, 314 (1978) (same). |
↑23 | See United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am. (“Alcoa”), 148 F.2d 416, 428 (2d Cir. 1945) (“[T]he vice of restrictive contracts and of monopoly is really one, it is the denial to commerce of the supposed protection of competition.”); N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 4–5 (1958) (“The Sherman Act was designed to be a comprehensive charter of economic liberty aimed at preserving free and unfettered competition as the rule of trade. It rests on the premise that the unrestrained interaction of competitive forces will yield the best allocation of our economic resources, the lowest prices, the highest quality and the greatest material progress, while at the same time providing an environment conductive to the preservation of our democratic political and social institutions. But even were that premise open to question, the policy unequivocally laid down by the Act is competition.”). |
↑24 | See Alcoa, 148 F.2d at 427–29 (“The [Sherman] Act has wider purposes…. Many people believe that possession of unchallenged economic power deadens initiative, discourages thrift and depresses energy; that immunity from competition is a narcotic, and rivalry is a stimulant, to industrial progress; that the spur of constant stress is necessary to counteract an inevitable disposition to let well enough alone. Such people believe that competitors, versed in the craft as no consumer can be, will be quick to detect opportunities for saving and new shifts in production, and be eager to profit by them.”). |
↑25 | See Line Material, 333 U.S. at 309 (“[O]ur economy is built largely upon competition in quality and prices.”); Alcoa, 148 F.2d at 427–29 (explaining these points at length). |
↑26 | See Asahi, 204 Cal. App. at 20 (“[T]he Cartwright Act, like all antitrust laws, is about the protection of competition, not competitors.”); Cel-Tech Commc’ns, Inc. v. Los Angeles Cellular Tel. Co., 20 Cal. 4th 163, 186 (1999) (“[A]ntitrust laws were enacted for the protection of competition, not competitors.”) (quoting Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colorado, Inc., 479 U.S. 104, 115 (1986)). |
↑27 | See Qualcomm, 292 F. Supp. 3d at 974 (quoted above on this point). |
↑28 | See AT & T Mobility LLC v. AU Optronics Corp., 707 F.3d 1106, 1112–13 (9th Cir. 2013) (“Applying California law to anticompetitive conduct undertaken within California [that results in harm to consumers in another state] advances the Cartwright Act’s overarching goals of maximizing effective deterrence of antitrust violations, enforcing the state’s antitrust laws against those violations that do occur, and ensuring disgorgement of any ill-gotten proceeds.”); see also Allstate Ins. Co. v. Hague, 449 U.S. 302, 312–13 (1981) (“For a State’s substantive law to be selected in a constitutionally permissible manner, that State must have a significant contact or significant aggregation of contacts, creating state interests, such that choice of its law is neither arbitrary nor fundamentally unfair.”). |
↑29 | See Marsh v. Anesthesia Servs. Med. Grp., Inc., 200 Cal. App. 4th 480, 493 (2011) (“The Cartwright Act prohibits combinations in unreasonable restraint of trade. Certain restraints which lack redeeming virtue are conclusively presumed to be unreasonable and illegal, and constitute a per se illegal practice. For example, a horizontal combination (an anticompetitive agreement among competitors who are at the same level of distribution) is ordinarily illegal per se. Likewise, market division, and certain types of group boycotts are unlawful per se.”). |
↑30 | See Knevelbaard Dairies v. Kraft Foods, Inc., 232 F.3d 979, 986 (9th Cir. 2000) (“When a per se violation such as horizontal price fixing has occurred, there is no need to define a relevant market or to show that the defendants had power within the market. The California Supreme Court has held, under the Cartwright Act, that competitors who agree to fix prices are liable under the per se rule ‘[e]ven though the members of the price-fixing group were in no position to control the market.’”) (quoting Mailand v. Burckle, 20 Cal.3d 367, 376 (1978)). |
↑31 | See Marsh, 200 Cal. App. 4th at 493. |
↑32 | See id. |
↑33 | See id. |
↑34 | See id. |
↑35 | See Knevelbaard, 232 F.3d at 986 (“Foremost in the category of per se violations is horizontal price-fixing among competitors…. Under both California and federal law, agreements [between direct competitors] fixing or tampering with prices are illegal per se.”) (quoting Oakland–Alameda County Builders Exch. v. F.P. Lathrop Constr. Co., 4 Cal.3d 354, 363 (1971)). |
↑36 | See In re Cipro Cases I & II, 61 Cal. 4th 116, 148 (2015) (Under the Act, “businesses may not engage in a horizontal allocation of markets, with would-be competitors dividing up territories or customers. Such allocations afford each participant an enclave free from the danger of outside incursions, in which to exercise monopoly power and extract monopoly premiums.”). |
↑37 | See Knevelbaard, 232 F.3d at 986; Marsh, 200 Cal. App. 4th at 493. |
↑38 | See Marsh, 200 Cal. App. 4th at 493; Freeman v. San Diego Ass’n of Realtors, 77 Cal. App. 4th 171, 195 (1999) (“[I]t is a violation of the antitrust laws for a group of competitors with separate and independent economic interests, or a single competitor with sufficient leverage, to force another to boycott a competitor at the same level of distribution.”). |
↑39 | See Hahn v. Oregon Physicians’ Service, 860 F.2d 1501, 1509 (9th Cir. 1988) (setting forth the first three of the above four criteria); NYNEX Corp. v. Discon, Inc., 525 U.S. 128, 135 (1998) (indicating that the per se rule against group boycotts applies only when it entails a horizontal arrangement made by direct competitors); Northwest Wholesale Stationers, Inc. v. Pacific Stationery and Printing Co., 472 U.S. 284, 294 (1985) (a group boycott is unlawful per se when it has “involved joint efforts by a firm or firms to disadvantage competitors by either directly denying or persuading or coercing suppliers or customers to deny relationships the competitors need in the competitive struggle.”) (quoting L. Sullivan, Law of Antitrust at 261-62 (1977)); see also Klor’s, Inc. v. Broadway-Hale Stores, Inc., 359 U.S. 207, 212-14 (1959) (a group boycott organized at behest of dominant retailer and enforced by its suppliers against a targeted retailer was held to be unlawful per se under section 1 of the Sherman Act). |
↑40 | See Med. Ctr. at Elizabeth Place, LLC v. Atrium Health Sys., 922 F.3d 713, 724–25 (6th Cir. 2019) (“Because joint ventures often have procompetitive efficiencies, when a joint venture is itself challenged as anticompetitive, that claim is reviewed under the rule of reason. But when the conduct of the joint venture is challenged, the relationship of the challenged conduct to the joint venture is analyzed to see if the conduct is reasonably related to the joint venture’s procompetitive features (and therefore should be judged under the rule of reason), or is a naked restraint lurking beneath the veneer of a legitimate joint venture (and therefore deserves per se condemnation)”). |
↑41 | See Polk Bros. v. Forest City Enters., Inc., 776 F.2d 185, 188–89 (7th Cir. 1985) (naked restraints are horizontal covenants between competitors that exist merely to suppress competition; as such, they are unlawful per se; ancillary restraints are horizontal covenants between competitors that restrain their competition, but exist to facilitate “a larger endeavor whose success they promote;” as such, they are reviewed under the rule of reason). |
↑42 | See Theme Promotions, Inc. v. News Am. Mktg. FSI, 546 F.3d 991, 1000 (9th Cir. 2008) (“California courts have determined that vertical restraints of trade … are not per se unreasonable but instead are subject to a ‘rule of reason’ analysis.”); Flagship Theatres of Palm Desert, LLC v. Century Theatres, Inc., 55 Cal. App. 5th 381, 406–07 (2020) (“The California Supreme Court has not yet addressed the general treatment of vertical restraints under the Cartwright Act, nor has it considered exclusive dealing or vertical group boycott claims more specifically. But California Courts of Appeal generally analyze vertical restraints under the rule of reason.”) (providing numerous citations to other California decisions). |
↑43 | See UAS Mgmt., Inc. v. Mater Misericordiae Hosp., 169 Cal. App. 4th 357, 366 (2009) (“A tying arrangement typically involves a seller with monopoly or other extensive market power in a given product, who then refuses to sell that product unless the buyer buys (or agrees not to buy from seller’s competitor) a separate product over which the seller does not have extensive independent market power. Such arrangements are unlawful unless their effect on commerce is de minimis.”); Packaging Sys., Inc. v. PRC-Desoto Int’l, Inc., 268 F. Supp. 3d 1071, 1083 (C.D. Cal. 2017) (“A tying arrangement is a device used by a seller with market power in one product market to extend its market power to a distinct product market. To accomplish this objective, the seller conditions the sale of one product (the tying product) on the buyer’s purchase of a second product (the tied product). Tying arrangements are forbidden on the theory that, if the seller has market power over the tying product, the seller can leverage this market power through tying arrangements to exclude other sellers of the tied product. Both Section 1 of the Sherman Act and the Cartwright Act prohibit illegal tying arrangements, and the elements of a § 1 tying claim for the most part mirror that of the Cartwright Act. For a tying claim to suffer per se condemnation, a plaintiff must prove: (1) that the defendant tied together the sale of two distinct products or services; (2) that the defendant possesses enough economic power in the tying product market to coerce its customers into purchasing the tied product; and (3) that the tying arrangement affects a not insubstantial volume of commerce in the tied product market.”). |
↑44 | See Theme Promotions, 546 F.3d at 1001 (“[E]xclusive dealing contracts may harm competition, but may also have the effect of enhancing competition. Under the rule of reason analysis, an exclusive dealing contract is proscribed when it is probable that performance of the contract will foreclose competition in a substantial share of the affected line of commerce.”); Fisherman’s Wharf, 114 Cal. App. 4th at 335 (“In California, exclusive dealing arrangements are not deemed illegal per se. They may provide an incentive for the marketing of new products and a guarantee of quality-control distribution. They are proscribed when it is probable that performance of the contract will foreclose competition in a substantial share of the affected line of commerce. Consequently, a determination of illegality is tested under a rule of reason and requires knowledge and analysis of the line of commerce, the market area, and the affected share of the relevant market.”). |
↑45 | See In Cascade Health Solutions v. PeaceHealth, 515 F.3d 883, 897 (9th Cir. 2008) (“[B]undled discounts, while potentially procompetitive by offering bargains to consumers, can also pose the threat of anticompetitive impact by excluding less diversified but more efficient producers.”). |
↑46 | See Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm Inc., 501 F.3d 297, 314 (3d Cir. 2007) (“We hold that (1) in a consensus-oriented private standard-setting environment, (2) a patent holder’s intentionally false promise to license essential proprietary technology on FRAND terms, (3) coupled with an SDO’s reliance on that promise when including the technology in a standard, and (4) the patent holder’s subsequent breach of that promise, is actionable anticompetitive conduct.”). |
↑47 | See Princo Corp. v. Int’l Trade Comm’n, 616 F.3d 1318, 1321 (Fed. Cir. 2010) (“[T]he doctrine [of patent misuse] limits a patentee’s right to impose conditions on a licensee that exceed the scope of the patent right”); id., 616 F.3d at 1327 (“[T]he basic rule of patent misuse: that the patentee may exploit his patent but may not use it to acquire a monopoly not embraced in the patent.”); see also United States v. Singer Mfg. Co., 374 U.S. 174, 196–97 (1963) (“[T]he possession of a valid patent or patents does not give the patentee any exemption from the provisions of the Sherman Act beyond the limits of the patent monopoly. By aggregating patents in one control, the holder of the patents cannot escape the prohibitions of the Sherman Act. That Act imposes strict limitations on the concerted activities in which patent owners may lawfully engage, and those limitations have been exceeded in this case [in which defendants pooled their patents and enforced them for their mutual benefit and so as to exclude targeted competitors from their respective markets.]”). |
↑48 | See United States v. Apple, Inc., 791 F.3d 290, 320 (2d Cir. 2015) (“MFNs, though surely proper in many contexts, can be misused to anticompetitive ends in some cases.”); Blue Cross & Blue Shield United of Wis. v. Marshfield Clinic, 65 F.3d 1406, 1415 (7th Cir.1995) (same); see, e.g., Starr v. Sony BMG Music Ent., 592 F.3d 314, 324 (2d Cir. 2010) (defendants’ concealment of most-favored pricing provisions suggested that defendants had colluded unlawfully to avert price competition); Fed. Trade Comm’n v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 2:23-CV-01495-JHC, 2024 WL 4448815, at *6 (W.D. Wash. Sept. 30, 2024) (“Plaintiffs adequately allege that Amazon’s anti-discounting practices stifle price competition. Specifically, they aver that Amazon’s actions that prevent third-party sellers from offering discounts on other sites are anticompetitive because they foreclose price competition from those sellers elsewhere.”); see generally Jonathan B. Baker, “Vertical Restraints with Horizontal Consequences: Competitive Effects of “Most–Favored–Customer” Clauses,” 64 Antitrust L.J. 517, 520–21 (1996); Jonathan B. Baker & Judith A. Chevalier, “The Competitive Consequences of Most–Favored–Nation Provisions,” Antitrust, Spring 2013, passim. |
↑49 | See generally Phillip Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles and Their Application (Wolters Kluwer online, 2024), ¶¶ 1600–1823. |
↑50 | See Fisherman’s Wharf, 114 Cal. App. 4th at 317 (“The Cartwright Act targets contracts in restraint of trade and promotes a free market by proscribing trusts.”); Alfred M. Lewis, Inc. v. Warehousemen, Teamsters, Chauffeurs & Helpers Loc. Union No. 542, 163 Cal. App. 2d 771, 783 (1958) (Under the Act, “[a] prohibited combination comes into being through an agreement of two or more persons for the purpose of restraining trade or preventing competition.”). At common law, a contract in restraint of trade was one by which a covenantee (e.g., a master tradesman) obliged a covenantor (e.g., an apprentice) to accept excessive restraints on his ability to compete against the covenantee, particularly after ceasing to perform work for the covenantee. Such restraints were deemed void and therefore unenforceable if they were found to be “general”—i.e., insufficiently narrow in scope or duration.(((See Addyston, 85 F. at 279 (“From early times it was the policy of Englishmen to encourage trade in England, and to discourage those voluntary restraints which tradesmen were often induced to impose on themselves by contract. Courts recognized this public policy by refusing to enforce stipulations of this character. The objections to such restraints were mainly two. One was that by such contracts a man disabled himself from earning a livelihood…. The other was that such restraints tended to give the covenantee, the beneficiary of such restraints, a monopoly of the trade, from which he had thus excluded one competitor, and by the same mean might exclude others.”). |
↑51 | See Kolling v. Dow Jones & Co., 137 Cal. App. 3d 709, 720 (1982) (“[T]he ‘conspiracy’ or ‘combination’ necessary to support an antitrust action [under the Act] can be found where a supplier or producer, by coercive conduct, imposes restraints to which distributors involuntarily adhere. If a single trader pressures customers or dealers into adhering to resale price maintenance, territorial restrictions, exclusive dealing arrangements or illegal tie-ins, an unlawful combination is established, irrespective of any monopoly or conspiracy, and despite the recognized right of a producer to determine with whom it will deal.”); Qualcomm, 292 F. Supp. 3d at 974 (same). |
↑52 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 16600 (subject to specific exceptions set forth at sections 16601–16602.5, “every contract by which anyone is restrained from engaging in a lawful profession, trade, or business of any kind is to that extent void.”); Edwards v. Arthur Andersen LLP, 44 Cal. 4th 937, 945 (2008) (“Today in California, covenants not to compete are void, subject to several exceptions.”); Ixchel Pharma, LLC v. Biogen, Inc., 9 Cal. 5th 1130, 1149 (2020) (“[S]ection 16600 applies to business contracts.”); AMN Healthcare, Inc. v. Aya Healthcare Servs., Inc., 28 Cal. App. 5th 923, 935–36 (2018) (“Section 16600 expresses California’s strong public policy of protecting the right of its citizens to pursue any lawful employment and enterprise of their choice. California courts have consistently affirmed that section 16600 evinces a settled legislative policy in favor of open competition and employee mobility. The interests of the employee in his or her own mobility and betterment are deemed paramount to the competitive business interests of the employers, where neither the employee nor his or her new employer has committed any illegal act accompanying the employment change.”). |
↑53 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code §§ 16601–16602.5. |
↑54 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 16600.5(e)(2) (“…a prevailing employee, former employee, or prospective employee in an action based on a violation of this chapter shall be entitled to recover reasonable attorney’s fees and costs.”). |
↑55 | See Marin Cnty. Bd. of Realtors, Inc. v. Palsson, 16 Cal. 3d 920, 925 (1976) (“A long line of California cases has concluded that the Cartwright Act is patterned after the Sherman Act and both statutes have their roots in the common law. Consequently, federal cases interpreting the Sherman Act are applicable to problems arising under the Cartwright Act.”) (giving numerous citations to support this proposition). |
↑56 | See Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85, 100 (1984) (“Horizontal price fixing and output limitation are ordinarily condemned as a matter of law under an illegal per se approach because the probability that these practices are anticompetitive is so high; a per se rule is applied when the practice facially appears to be one that would always or almost always tend to restrict competition and decrease output. In such circumstances a restraint is presumed unreasonable without inquiry into the particular market context in which it is found.”). |
↑57 | See Nat’l Soc. of Pro. Eng’rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 692 (1978) (“There are, thus, two complementary categories of antitrust analysis. In the first category are agreements whose nature and necessary effect are so plainly anticompetitive that no elaborate study of the industry is needed to establish their illegality—they are ‘illegal per se.’ In the second category are agreements whose competitive effect can only be evaluated by analyzing the facts peculiar to the business, the history of the restraint, and the reasons why it was imposed.”). |
↑58 | See Law v. Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n, 134 F.3d 1010, 1020 (10th Cir. 1998) (a quick-look review is used when a trade restraint is not unlawful per se, but “has obvious anticompetitive effects,” in which case the court need not conduct a market analysis and can directly decide “whether the procompetitive justifications advanced for the restraint outweigh the anticompetitive effects.”). |
↑59 | See United States v. Am. Airlines Grp. Inc., 121 F.4th 209, 220 (1st Cir. 2024) (“A rule-of-reason analysis requires a fact-specific assessment of the restraint’s actual effect on competition. Under the rule of reason’s three-step burden-shifting framework, the plaintiff must first make a showing that the restraint has a substantial anticompetitive effect, which can be proven directly or indirectly. If the plaintiff carries that burden, the burden shifts to the defendant to show a procompetitive rationale for the restraint. And if the defendant makes this showing, then the burden shifts back to the plaintiff to demonstrate that the procompetitive efficiencies could be reasonably achieved through less anticompetitive means, or that on balance, the restraint’s harms outweigh its benefits.”). |
↑60 | See Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n v. Alston, 594 U.S. 69, 88 (2021) (“At one end of the spectrum, some restraints may be so obviously incapable of harming competition that they require little scrutiny.”). |
↑61 | See California Dental Ass’n v. F.T.C., 526 U.S. 756, 758 (1999) (“There is generally no categorical line between restraints giving rise to an intuitively obvious inference of anticompetitive effect and those that call for more detailed treatment. What is required is an enquiry meet for the case, looking to a restraint’s circumstances, details, and logic.”). |
↑62 | See Bhan v. NME Hosps., Inc., 929 F.2d 1404, 1413 (9th Cir. 1991) (“To meet his initial burden [for a rule-of-reason challenge under Section 1], plaintiff must show that the activity is the type that restrains trade and that the restraint is likely to be of significant magnitude. Ordinarily, a plaintiff to do this must delineate a relevant market and show that the defendant plays enough of a role in that market to impair competition significantly.”); Spanish Broad. Sys. of Fla., Inc. v. Clear Channel Commc’ns, Inc., 376 F.3d 1065, 1072 (11th Cir. 2004) (A plaintiff can meet its initial burden under Section 1 by showing that “the [challenged] behavior had the potential for genuine adverse effects on competition.”); FTC v. Indiana Fed’n of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 460–61 (1986) (In Section 1 cases, “the purpose of the inquiries into market definition and market power is to determine whether an arrangement has the potential for genuine adverse effects on competition”); Eichorn v. AT & T Corp., 248 F.3d 131, 144–45 (3d Cir. 2001) (“Under the rule of reason, we look at the totality of the circumstances surrounding an alleged anti-competitive activity. … In applying this test, we examine the competitive significance of the alleged restraint to determine whether it has an anti-competitive effect on the market and is an unreasonable restraint on trade.”). |
↑63 | See Bhan, 929 F.2d at 1413 (“Should the plaintiff satisfy his initial burden, the defendant must offer evidence of pro-competitive effects. The plaintiff, driven to this point, must then try to show that any legitimate objectives can be achieved in a substantially less restrictive manner. Finally, the court must weigh the harms and benefits to determine if the behavior is reasonable on balance.”). |
↑64 | See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 58–59 (D.C. Cir. 2001). |
↑65 | See Marin Cnty. Bd. of Realtors, 16 Cal. 3d at 925. |
↑66 | See Theme, 546 F.3d at 1001 (to prove a rule-of-reason violation of the Act, the plaintiff usually “must first define the relevant market and then show that the defendant plays enough of a role in the market to impair competition significantly.”); Exxon Corp. v. Superior Ct., 51 Cal. App. 4th 1672, 1681 (1997) (to prevail on rule-of-reason claim under the Act, a plaintiff must “make the required showing of a substantially adverse effect on competition in the relevant market.”); Dang v. San Francisco Forty Niners, 964 F. Supp. 2d 1097, 1104 (N.D. Cal. 2013) (“In order to state a valid antitrust claim [under the Act or the Sherman Act], a plaintiff must allege that the defendant has market power within a legally cognizable relevant market.”). |
↑67 | See Fed. Trade Comm’n v. Qualcomm Inc., 969 F.3d 974, 992 (9th Cir. 2020) (“A threshold step in any antitrust case is to accurately define the relevant market, which refers to the area of effective competition. Courts usually cannot properly apply the rule of reason without an accurate definition of the relevant market. Otherwise, there is no way to measure the defendant’s ability to lessen or destroy competition.”); Image Tech. Servs., Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195, 1202 (9th Cir. 1997) (“The relevant market is the field in which meaningful competition is said to exist.”). |
↑68 | See Dang, 964 F. Supp. 2d at (“While the definition of a relevant market for antitrust purposes is typically a factual inquiry, certain legal principles govern the definition, and antitrust claims may be dismissed under Rule 12(b)(6) if the plaintiff’s relevant market definition is facially unsustainable.”). |
↑69 | See United States v. Rockford Mem’l Corp., 898 F.2d 1278, 1285 (7th Cir. 1990) (“It is always possible to take pot shots at a market definition (we have just taken one), and the defendants do so with vigor and panache. Their own proposal, however, is ridiculous—a ten-county area in which it is assumed (without any evidence and contrary to common sense) that Rockford residents, or third-party payors, will be searching out small, obscure hospitals in remote rural areas if the prices charged by the hospitals in Rockford rise above competitive levels. Forced to choose between two imperfect market definitions, the defendants’ and the district judge’s (the latter a considerable expansion of the government’s tiny proposed market) … we choose the less imperfect, the district judge’s.”). |
↑70 | See Fed. Trade Comm’n v. Penn State Hershey Med. Ctr., 838 F.3d 327, 338 (3d Cir. 2016) (In antitrust cases, “[t]he relevant market is defined in terms of two components: the product market and the geographic market.”). |
↑71 | See Exxon, 51 Cal. App. 4th at 1682 (“The United States Supreme Court has declared that the relevant market is determined by considering ‘commodities reasonably interchangeable by consumers for the same purposes.’ Or, in other words, the relevant market is composed of products that have reasonable interchangeability for the purpose for which they are produced.”) (quoting United States v. E.I. duPont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 395 (1956)); Thurman Indus., Inc. v. Pay ‘N Pak Stores, Inc., 875 F.2d 1369, 1374 (9th Cir. 1989) (“[A] product market is typically defined to include the pool of goods or services that qualify as economic substitutes because they enjoy reasonable interchangeability of use and cross-elasticity of demand.”). |
↑72 | See Penn State Hershey, 838 F.3d at 338 (“The relevant geographic market is that area in which a potential buyer may rationally look for the goods or services he seeks. Determined within the specific context of each case, a market’s geographic scope must correspond to the commercial realities of the industry being considered and be economically significant.”). |
↑73 | See Penn State Hershey, 838 F.3d at 338 (“A common method employed by courts and the FTC to determine the relevant geographic market is the hypothetical monopolist test. Under the Horizontal Merger Guidelines issued by the U.S. Department of Justice’s Antitrust Division and the FTC, if a hypothetical monopolist could impose a small but significant non-transitory increase in price (‘SSNIP’) in the proposed market, the market is properly defined. If, however, consumers would respond to a SSNIP by purchasing the product from outside the proposed market, thereby making the SSNIP unprofitable, the proposed market definition is too narrow.”). |
↑74 | See Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 482 (1992) (“The proper market definition in this case can be determined only after a factual inquiry into the ‘commercial realities’ faced by consumers.”) (quotation marks in original). |
↑75 | See Theme, 546 F.3d at 1002 (Under the Act, “[a] relevant market is identified by considering commodities reasonably interchangeable by consumers for the same purposes. Put another way, the relevant market includes all sellers or producers who have actual or potential ability to deprive each other of significant levels of business.”). |
↑76 | See In re Ins. Brokerage Antitrust Litig., 618 F.3d 300, 317 (3d Cir. 2010) (“While pleading exclusively per se violations can lighten a plaintiff’s litigation burdens, it is not a riskless strategy. If the court determines that the restraint at issue is sufficiently different from the per se archetypes to require application of the rule of reason, the plaintiff’s claims will be dismissed.”). |
↑77 | See Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl–O–Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 489 (1977) (An antitrust injury is one that “should reflect the anticompetitive effect either of the violation or of anticompetitive acts made possible by the violation.”); Rebel Oil Co. v. Atl. Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1433 (9th Cir. 1995) (The doctrine of antitrust injury requires a private plaintiff to “prove that his loss flows from an anticompetitive aspect or effect of the defendant’s behavior….”); Atl. Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328, 344 (1990) (“The antitrust injury requirement ensures that a plaintiff can recover only if the loss stems from a competition-reducing aspect or effect of the defendant’s behavior.”). |
↑78 | See Clayworth v. Pfizer, Inc., 49 Cal. 4th 758, 787 (2010) (“[I]n an antitrust price-fixing case, the presumptive measure of damages is the amount of the overcharge paid by the plaintiff.”); Glen Holly Ent., Inc. v. Tektronix, Inc., 352 F.3d 367, 374 (9th Cir. 2003) (“The [challenged] agreement detrimentally changed the market make-up and limited consumers’ choice to one source of output. One form of antitrust injury is coercive activity that prevents its victims from making free choices between market alternatives.”). |
↑79 | See Knevelbaard, 232 F.3d at 988 (9th Cir. 2000) (Plaintiffs, who supplied milk to cheese producers, stated actionable antitrust injury under the Act by plausibly alleging that these producers had colluded to depress the prices that they paid for plaintiffs’ milk). |
↑80 | See Catch Curve, Inc. v. Venali, Inc., 519 F. Supp. 2d 1028, 1035-36 (C.D. Cal. 2007) (A competitor suffers antitrust injury if the defendant uses wrongful exclusionary conduct to hinder or prevent it from competing, so that the defendant can acquire or preserve market power); see also W. Penn Allegheny Health Sys., Inc. v. UPMC, 627 F.3d 85, 102 (3d Cir. 2010) (An antitrust injury occurs to a competitor or other market participant when its “injuries are the means by which the defendants seek to achieve their anticompetitive end.”). |
↑81 | See W. Penn Allegheny, 627 F.3d at 101 (“The antitrust-injury requirement helps ensure that the harm claimed by the plaintiff corresponds to the rationale for finding a violation of the antitrust laws in the first place….”). |
↑82 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code §§ 16750(a), 16761; Borgeson v. Archer-Daniels Midland Co., 909 F. Supp. 709, 717 (C.D. Cal. 1995) (“In addition to establishing a public cause of action (enforced by the State Attorney General), the Cartwright Act gives a private right to sue for damages and treble damages to each person who suffers harm.”); Carver v. Chevron U.S.A., Inc., 119 Cal. App. 4th 498, 504 (2004) (“The public policy implicit in the unilateral fee–shifting provision of section 16750, subdivision (a) is to encourage injured parties to broadly and effectively enforce the Cartwright Act in situations where they otherwise would not find it economical to sue. The Legislature clearly intended to give special treatment to antitrust claims under the Cartwright Act by creating this one-way fee-shifting right for a successful plaintiff but not for a defendant who successfully defends such a claim.”). |
↑83 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code §§ 16750(c)–(g), 16754, 16760. |
↑84 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 16750(a), (c). |
↑85 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 16755(a). |
↑86 | See F. & A. Ice Cream Co. v. Arden Farms Co., 98 F. Supp. 180, 190–191 (S.D. Cal. 1951) (confirming this point). |
↑87 | See, e.g., United States v. Aiyer, 33 F.4th 97, 109 (2d Cir. 2022) (a recent, successful criminal prosecution for price-fixing and bid-rigging); see also U.S. Dept of Just., Just. Manual § 7-1.100 (2020) (“When it comes to enforcement, the Division’s policy, in general, is to proceed by criminal investigation and prosecution in cases involving horizontal, ‘per se’ unlawful agreements such as price fixing, bid rigging, and market allocation.”). |
↑88 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code §§ 16750(c)–(g), 16754, 16755(a). |
↑89 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code §§ 16750(a); Carver, 119 Cal. App. 4th at 503 (“The Cartwright Act contains a unilateral fee–shifting provision that allows an award of attorney fees to a prevailing plaintiff but not to a prevailing defendant.”). |
↑90 | See Cal. Code Civ. Proc. § 128.5(a) (“A trial court may order a party, the party’s attorney, or both, to pay the reasonable expenses, including attorney’s fees, incurred by another party as a result of actions or tactics, made in bad faith, that are frivolous or solely intended to cause unnecessary delay.”); Fed. R. Civ. P. 11 (subjects plaintiff’s attorney or a pro se plaintiff to sanctions for making claims or other court submissions in bad faith); Cal. Code Civ. Proc. § 128.7 (directly analogous to Fed. R. Civ. P. 11). |
↑91 | See Kumar v. Ramsey, 71 Cal. App. 5th 1110, 1120–21 (2021) (“Like its federal counterpart … rule 11 of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure, Code of Civil Procedure section 128.7 should be utilized only in the rare and exceptional case where the action is clearly frivolous, legally unreasonable or without legal foundation, or brought for an improper purpose. Because our adversary system requires that attorneys and litigants be provided substantial breathing room to develop and assert factual and legal arguments, section 128.7 sanctions should not be routinely or easily awarded even for a claim that is arguably frivolous, and instead should be made with restraint.”). |
↑92 | See Bertero v. Nat’l Gen. Corp., 13 Cal. 3d 43, 50 (1974) (“To establish a cause of action for the malicious prosecution of a civil proceeding, a plaintiff must plead and prove that the prior action (1) was commenced by or at the direction of the defendant and was pursued to a legal termination in his, plaintiff’s favor; (2) was brought without probable cause; and (3) was initiated with malice.”); Zamos v. Stroud, 32 Cal. 4th 958, 970 (2004) (An attorney can be held liable for malicious prosecution when he files an untenable claim or continues “to prosecute a lawsuit discovered to lack probable cause.”). |
↑93 | See Albertson v. Raboff, 46 Cal. 2d 375, 383 (1956) (“The malice required in an action for malicious prosecution is not limited to actual hostility or ill will toward plaintiff but exists when the proceedings are instituted primarily for an improper purpose…. [T]he principal situations in which the civil proceedings are initiated for an improper purpose [include] … proceedings … initiated for the purpose of forcing a settlement which has no relation to the merits of the claim.”). |
↑94 | See Jay v. Mahaffey, 218 Cal. App. 4th 1522, 1539 (2013) (“[M]alicious prosecution is a disfavored action. The elements of malicious prosecution have historically been carefully circumscribed so that litigants with potentially valid claims will not be deterred from bringing their claims to court by the prospect of a subsequent malicious prosecution claim.”). |
↑95 | See Sycamore Ridge Apartments, LLC v. Naumann, 157 Cal. App. 4th 1385, 1402 (2007) (“A litigant will lack probable cause for his action either if he relies upon facts which he has no reasonable cause to believe to be true, or if he seeks recovery upon a legal theory which is untenable under the facts known to him.”). |
↑96 | See AT & T Mobility, 707 F.3d at 1112–13 (“Applying California law to anticompetitive conduct undertaken within California [that results in harm to consumers in another state] advances the Cartwright Act’s overarching goals of maximizing effective deterrence of antitrust violations, enforcing the state’s antitrust laws against those violations that do occur, and ensuring disgorgement of any ill-gotten proceeds.”); see also Allstate, 449 U.S. at 312–13 (“For a State’s substantive law to be selected in a constitutionally permissible manner, that State must have a significant contact or significant aggregation of contacts, creating state interests, such that choice of its law is neither arbitrary nor fundamentally unfair.”). |
↑97 | See Qualcomm, 292 F. Supp. 3d at 974 (“The Cartwright Act proscribes ‘a combination of capital, skill or acts by two or more persons’ for an unlawful purpose. By its terms, the Act does not cover ‘wrongful conduct on the part of a single entity.’”) (quoting Bondi, 267 Cal. App.2d at 678); Asahi, 204 Cal. App. at 11 (“[A]n indispensable element of any action under the Cartwright Act is proof of a ‘combination of resources of two or more independent interests for the purpose of restraining commerce and preventing market competition.’”) (quoting G.H.I.I., 147 Cal. App.3d at 266). |
↑98 | See Dimidowich v. Bell & Howell, 803 F.2d 1473, 1478 (9th Cir. 1987), opinion modified on denial of reh’g, 810 F.2d 1517 (9th Cir. 1987). |
↑99 | See Texaco, 46 Cal. 3d at 1168. |
↑100 | See Kolling, 137 Cal. App. 3d at 720. |
↑101 | See California v. ARC Am. Corp., 490 U.S. 93, 102 (1989) (“[F]ederal antitrust laws do not pre-empt state law.”); see also Redwood Theatres, Inc. v. Festival Enterprises, Inc., 908 F.2d 477, 480 (9th Cir. 1990) (“California courts have held that the Cartwright Act applies to transactions in interstate commerce.”). |
↑102 | See Selevan, 584 F.3d at 90 (“In implementing the Commerce Clause, the Supreme Court has adhered strictly to the principle that the right to engage in interstate commerce is not the gift of a state, and that a state cannot regulate or restrain it. It flows from this principle that the negative or dormant implication of the Commerce Clause [of the U.S. Constitution] prohibits state taxation or regulation that discriminates against or unduly burdens interstate commerce and thereby impedes free private trade in the national marketplace.”); Quik Payday, Inc. v. Stork, 549 F.3d 1302, 1307 (10th Cir. 2008) (“The Supreme Court long has recognized that the affirmative grant of authority to Congress to regulate interstate commerce also encompasses an implicit or ‘dormant’ limitation on the authority of the States to enact legislation affecting interstate commerce. State statutes may violate the dormant limitation in three ways: First, a statute that clearly discriminates against interstate commerce in favor of intrastate commerce is virtually invalid per se and can survive only if the discrimination is demonstrably justified by a valid factor unrelated to economic protectionism. Second, if the statute does not discriminate against interstate commerce, it will nevertheless be invalidated under the Pike balancing test if it imposes a burden on interstate commerce incommensurate with the local benefits secured. Third, a statute will be invalid per se if it has the practical effect of extraterritorial control of commerce occurring entirely outside the boundaries of the state in question.”); Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., 397 U.S. 137, 142 (1970) (“Where the statute regulates even-handedly to effectuate a legitimate local public interest, and its effects on interstate commerce are only incidental, it will be upheld unless the burden imposed on such commerce is clearly excessive in relation to the putative local benefits. If a legitimate local purpose is found, then the question becomes one of degree. And the extent of the burden that will be tolerated will of course depend on the nature of the local interest involved, and on whether it could be promoted as well with a lesser impact on interstate activities.”). |
↑103 | See SC Manufactured Homes, 162 Cal. App. 4th at 84 (“The [Act] prohibits conspiracies that unreasonably restrain trade.”); Asahi, 204 Cal. App. at 11 (2012) (“[A]n indispensable element of any action under the Cartwright Act is proof of a ‘combination of resources of two or more independent interests for the purpose of restraining commerce and preventing market competition.’”) (quoting G.H.I.I., 147 Cal. App.3d at 266). |
↑104 | See Fisherman’s Wharf, 114 Cal. App. 4th at 317 (“The Cartwright Act targets contracts in restraint of trade and promotes a free market by proscribing trusts.”); Kolling, 137 Cal. App. 3d at 720 (“[T]he ‘conspiracy’ or ‘combination’ necessary to support an antitrust action [under the Act] can be found where a supplier or producer, by coercive conduct, imposes restraints to which distributors involuntarily adhere. If a single trader pressures customers or dealers into adhering to resale price maintenance, territorial restrictions, exclusive dealing arrangements or illegal tie-ins, an unlawful combination is established, irrespective of any monopoly or conspiracy, and despite the recognized right of a producer to determine with whom it will deal.”); Qualcomm, 292 F. Supp. 3d at 974 (same). |
↑105 | See Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 16750(a); Stanislaus, 782 F. Supp. 2d at 1080 (“Unlike the federal Sherman Act, the Cartwright Act grants indirect purchasers standing to sue, as well as direct purchasers.”). |
↑106 | See Texaco, 46 Cal. 3d at 1168 (the Act does not govern anticompetitive mergers or acquisitions); Qualcomm, 292 F. Supp. 3d at 974; (“The Cartwright Act proscribes ‘a combination of capital, skill or acts by two or more persons’ for an unlawful purpose. By its terms, the Act does not cover ‘wrongful conduct on the part of a single entity.’”) (quoting Bondi, 267 Cal. App.2d at 678). |
↑107 | See id. |
↑108 | See Texaco, 46 Cal. 3d at 1153–1169 (extended explanation of these points with citations to numerous authorities); Cipro, 61 Cal. 4th at 142 (“Interpretations of federal antitrust law are at most instructive, not conclusive, when construing the Cartwright Act, given that the Cartwright Act was modeled not on federal antitrust statutes but instead on statutes enacted by California’s sister states around the turn of the 20th century.”) (citing Aryeh v. Canon Business Solutions, Inc., 55 Cal. 4th 1185, 1195 (2013)); Freeman, 77 Cal. App. 4th at 183 (“In analyzing [plaintiff’s] Cartwright Act claims we frequently examine federal precedent because the Cartwright Act is similar in language and purpose to the Sherman Act. However, federal precedents must be used with caution because the acts, although similar, are not coextensive.”). |